The Lincoln Log:
Abe’s Monetary Policy
4/23/2015
This weekend Prime Minister Shinzo Abe
will arrive in Washington. In the
following week, a bevy of LDP Diet members will also descend upon Washington in
the annual Golden Week trek.
Obviously, the big attention-grabbing issue is what language Prime
Minister Abe will use in his address to the joint session of Congress to speak
about the Comfort Women and other historical issues (an attention that is
altogether proper).
But whatever he says, he and his supporters will try to soften the
potential negative reaction to his view of history by talking up the success of
“Abenomics.” That is, even if we
(and the Koreans and Chinese) do not like what the Prime Minister has to say
about history, we should be thankful that he is rescuing the Japanese economy. After all, it was the willingness of the
Japanese public to hold their noses about his offensive right-wing nationalism
in a hope that his economic policies would be better than sorry record of the
Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ) prime ministers in office 2009 to the end of
2012.
The goal of Abenomics was to achieve 2
percent real GDP growth and 2 percent consumer price inflation within 2 years
(i.e. by the end of March, 2015).
Their story will be that while the targets have not been reached, all
Japan needs is a little more time because fundamentally the policies are
working. The one piece of
Abenomics that most of them will tout as being more or less on target, albeit a
bit more slowly than anticipated, is monetary policy. But their story is unduly optimistic.
Spoiler alert: deflation is not over
What is on target is the Bank of
Japan’s goal of doubling the monetary base over a two period, beginning from
April, 2013. That goal was
considered to be a radical policy for the normally conservative Bank of
Japan. According to Bank of Japan
data, the monetary base (currency in circulation plus commercial bank
reserves—a technical term that should not be confused with the money supply)
was 218% higher in March 2015 than it was in March 2013. Voilà!! They have achieved their goal in
doubling the monetary base.
But what about the intended outcome of
this monetary expansion of creating 2 percent consumer price inflation? This turns out to be a somewhat
confusing issue because of the 3 percentage-point increase in the national
consumption tax (a sales tax levied on most consumer goods and services). In addition, energy prices have gyrated
in the past two years, further muddying the data. But you can be sure that Prime Minister and various visiting
LDP Diet members will find ways to describe the data to support the notion that
the economy is on track to producing 2 percent inflation. Not exactly.
On the following page is a chart
showing the raw consumer price index (with a base year of 2010 = 100) on a
monthly basis. As you can see,
there is a jump in the index in April 2015 because of the tax increase. The chart shows two versions of the
consumer price index—the full index covering all goods and services consumed by
households, and one excluding food and energy. Economists prefer to exclude both food and energy because
they are so volatile and therefore muddy any attempt to discern underlying
trends. The Japanese government
prefers a “Japanese core” index that only excludes food (I have no idea why),
but that one remains affected by volatile energy prices so I will skip in this
analysis. To be sure, changing
energy prices eventually feed through the economic system and affect prices of
all goods and services that use energy (such as airline fares being affected by
the price of aviation fuel, which, in turn, is affected by the price of crude
oil).
So what does this chart show? Consumer prices were rising slowly in
the year from January 2013 to April 2015.
Since then, however, the trend of the index—both for all items and the
one excluding food and energy appear to have flattened or even declined.
Rather than looking at the actual index
number, economists prefer to look at measures of the change over time. There are two ways of doing this: comparing one month to the previous
month, or comparing one month to the same month in the previous year (called a
year-on-year comparison). Because
monthly economic data of any sort if often subject to random short-term events,
generally economists use the year-on-year comparison. But in this case, it is useful to look at both.
If we look at the usual
year-on-year comparison, the result is shown in the chart on the following
page. In the few months preceding
the start of “Abenomics” monetary policy (which began in April 2013 after Mr.
Kuroda was appointed as the new governor of the Bank of Japan by Prime Minister
Abe), consumer prices were still falling at a rate of -0.5 percent or a bit
more. Thereafter, prices did begin
to rise. Part of that rise was
simply due to the rising price of crude oil (and the increasing importance of
that more expensive oil due to the shutdown of all nuclear power plants in the
year subsequent to the 2011 Tohoku earthquake/tsunami/nuclear disaster). By March 2014, just before the
consumption tax increased, the overall consumer price index was rising at a year-on-year rate of 1.5 percent
and even the index minus food
and energy was rising at 0.8 percent.
While well short of the 2 percent goal, the trend appeared to be in the
right direction.
When the
tax rate jumped from 5 percent to 8 percent in April, obviously the change in
consumer prices increased. While
the tax applies to most consumer goods and services (e.g. housing construction)
it does not apply to them all (school tuition fees, for example, are
exempt). In any case, in February
2015 (the latest data available), the overall price index was running about 2.2
percent higher than a year earlier, and the index minus food and energy was 2
percent. Quite likely these are
the numbers that Japanese visitors during Golden Week will tout as showing
success of Abenomics monetary policy.
But what happens if we look at the
month-to-month change in prices?
The chart on the following page gives those results. Remember, in this case we are looking
at the change in prices in one month compared to the immediately preceding
month (the change from January to February 2015, for example). The numbers here are very small. After all, if prices increase 1 percent
year-on-year, then they changed month-to-month by less than 0.1 percent. And one can see that the changes do
jump around somewhat from month to month.
However, there are several interesting results from looking at these
numbers.
First, prices had begun to rise just
before Governor Kuroda got his Bank of Japan Policy Board to embark on
quantitative easing. Second,
prices were generally rising slightly month by month after quantitative easing
began (except for January 2014).
Third, the spike due to the consumption tax increase becomes very
obvious. In April, 2014 prices
jumped 2 percent (both the overall index and the index minus food and
energy). Fourth, prices since
April, 2014 have not continued rising.
The explanation that will be put forth by visitors to Washington will be
that this is a temporary phenomenon due to falling oil prices. But the data show the same result for
the price index minus food and energy.
These data imply that initially
quantitative easing appeared to have a small positive impact on prices in its
first year of operation. But in
the year since the tax increase in April 2014, that positive effect on prices
has petered out. Let’s go back to
the actual index to measure the changes over time. Leaving out food and energy, overall consumer prices rose
1.3 percent in the year from April, 2013 through March, 2014 (i.e. the index
was 1.3 percent higher in March, 2014 than in April 2013). Part of that increase was due to
increasing oil prices, so the price index minus food and energy rose a much
smaller 0.2 percent. Still
positive, but not anything to shout about. But from April 2014 through February
2015, the overall price index fell by 0.2 percent and the index minus food and
energy fell by 0.3 percent. Not
only did the price increases stall, but the drop in prices cannot be blamed on
the external factor of declining oil prices.
This is quite discouraging—quantitative
easing appeared to be having some positive effect (even if the impact once oil
price increases are factored out was quite small), but that effect has worn
off. Since late 2014 prices have
resumed a resumed a mild decline.
Japan is not yet out of deflation.
But what about the stories of wage
increases? No doubt this
development will also be brought up by Japanese visitors. Toyota and some other large
manufacturers have been persuaded by the government to increase wages. Won’t this help to keep prices rising
as firms have to pass along the cost impact of higher wages? That’s another whole story not worth
getting into in this short note.
But briefly: What the
large, politically sensitive Toyota does in bargaining with its union and what
happens to all wages in Japan are not necessarily the same thing (remember that
just like in the United States, only a small proportion of the labor force is
unionized). More important, firms
were so stingy in granting wage increases last year, that even a 2 percent wage
increase will do no more than restore the losses workers suffered due to
stagnant wages in the face of the consumption tax increase. No need from that for firms to start
increasing prices.
Is there a way to draw a more
optimistic picture? Maybe. One effect of monetary quantitative
easing has been a rather dramatic fall in the value of the yen against other
currencies. This weakening of the
currency is finally producing an increase in exports. As exports rise, so does employment in the manufacturing
sector. With a falling working-age
population, increased employment in export-oriented manufacturing causes labor
markets to tighten and could possibly produce higher wages—not because the
government jawbones companies like Toyota, but because they can get more
workers only by paying more. That
might lead to higher prices. But
it is too early to tell if this will really happen (it did not happen during
the rapid export expansion of 2002-2007).
At least for the near future, therefore, Japan is not out of the woods
on deflation. So listen to the
upbeat talk from Prime Minister Abe and his fellow LDP politicians with a very
large dose of skepticism.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Intelligent comments and additional information welcome. We are otherwise selective.